Eurozone bailout policies in crisis: A novel win-win approach is needed
Economic growth-linked bonds convertible to natural gas for Cyprus Robert Shiller suggested we can solve the debt crisis by issuing bonds linked to GDP and that “the opportunity to participate in the uncertain economic growth of the issuer might well excite, rather than scare off, investors—just as it does in the stock market.” (HBR, 2012) EU politicians have been locked in recent years in myopic and often self-defeating policies regarding bailout of troubled eurozone countries. They have insisted, in principle correctly, that troubled countries bring their finances to a sustainable path. But the chosen austerity measures oftentimes choke the sovereign economies killing their growth prospects and damaging their very ability to repay the lenders. And the less able the borrowers become, the tougher the repayment terms, leading to a vicious cycle of further deterioration and sequels of ineffective rescue packages. The European Central Bank recently stated that eurozone countries in rescue programs must regain full access to sovereign bond markets before being able to apply for ECB help to lower borrowing costs under the new OMT program. So the high borrowing costs facing troubled economies with poor credit rating will remain a key challenge. New approaches are desperately needed. One alternative is to make the coupon interest paid on rescue loans variable and linked to the rate of growth of the country’s economy. In the downward phase when the economy is in recession, the interest burden will be lower, helping the country to boost growth; when in the future economic growth picks up, GDP-linked payments will be higher precisely when the country can afford it. Moreover, the higher interest payments in the upward phase of the economy will constrain politicians from generous increases in public spending, a likely cause of trouble in the first place. In essence, during recession EU lenders will be providing insurance and interest subsidy to troubled Eurozone members, helping them to pull themselves up, in exchange for higher growth potential during good times. Markets price such instruments daily (e.g., via interest-rate swaps), setting a variable rate (e.g., LIBOR + spread) that is a fair exchange for a fixed rate. The spread is analogous to an insurance premium. If the instrument provides a hedge benefit or significant upside potential, the premium might even be negative. Suppose the fixed interest rate on a rescue loan by Troika is 3%, and Cyprus’ steady-state GDP growth rate is 4%. In the case of GDP-linked bonds for Cyprus, for example, the interest rate might be GDP growth -1%. If GDP growth next year is 0%, the interest will be a subsidy of 1% helping economic recovery. If after 10 years GDP growth will be 7%, the interest will be higher, at 6%. It is possible to set a floor below which interest payments will not fall, e.g., 0%, which also can be fairly priced in. In exchange for this downside protection option given to lenders, the spread might narrow. Alternatively, there can be an offsetting cap protecting the issuing government against excessively high payments beyond a specified threshold. Economic growth-linked bonds have obvious benefits for affected countries: they reduce cyclical vulnerability for troubled or developing economies, while preventing misuse of excess funds by politicians in expansion times. By lowering the interest due in hard times they help stabilize government spending and avoid the need for excessive social spending cuts that hurt the poorest levels of society; they also help them pull out of recessions and reduce the likelihood of sovereign default and debt crises. GDP-linked bonds may be attractive to investors, interested in an equity-like position on specific countries’ growth prospects. For example, Cyprus currently has a struggling banking sector and stock market, but promising long-term growth prospects due to its natural gas discoveries. The correlation among these investing possibilities is not that high. The international investor may not be willing to bet on Cyprus’ stock market or banking sector, but may well be willing (perhaps even excited) to take an option on its natural gas prospects or long-term GDP growth. Evidence from the financial markets confirms that investors are willing to accept lower average returns in the short-term in exchange for a chance at high future growth potential. In fact, many important businesses, such as venture capital, pharmaceuticals or the movie industry, owe their success to actively managing such portfolios of (low probability) high growth prospects. GDP-linked bonds would provide broader benefits to the global financial system. By helping reduce the risk of sovereign defaults and contagion effects, they would strengthen EU stability and the global financial system. The European Commission, the ECB, IMF, even the World Bank and the United Nations, should all encourage a global market for GDP-linked bonds. This will provide a unique global investment opportunity to achieve valuable risk diversification benefits, while preserving the advantages of positively skewed distribution of returns. If growth prospects across emerging markets are less correlated, global investors should actually improve their return/risk performance. This is also a way for rich but low-growth countries to obtain a stake in high-prospect countries currently in trouble, as a fair exchange for their current support to recovery and realization of growth potential. This is a common-sense proposition that is in their best interest and provides a win-win solution out of the prolonged crisis. There is little doubt that many institutional investors would be attracted. Sovereign funds, hedge funds and others interested to have stakes on growth would be natural customers. International risk diversification with upside growth potential would appeal to insurance and pension funds. Domestic pension funds in troubled economies might invest to obtain an inflation hedge and a growth stake. Investors are well familiar already with inflation-linked bonds, protecting bond returns from price increases. However, inflation-linked bonds offer little upside exposure to economic expansion. Nominal GDP-linked debt combines the advantages of inflation protection and real growth prospects of growth stocks in one. If the country has natural resources or commodities (e.g., oil for Mexico or gas for Cyprus), these instruments can capture the advantages of an option as well. As with any idea to be put in practice, there are legitimate concerns, which can be mitigated through careful design. The difficulty of pricing such instruments can be mitigated by keeping the structure as simple as possible. For example, these bonds should not be callable by the issuer when growth exceeds a threshold (as was done in Bulgaria) as that would remove the growth incentive. A critical mass and standardization of terms across issues would help to achieve market liquidity and facilitate pricing. This would also allow securitization in the international market. Market swaps of fixed-rate and GDP linked bonds may facilitate price discovery. Some might argue that the yield on a GDP-linked bond is more variable and should require a premium over a similar fixed-rate bond. However, given that the correlation between a typical troubled or an emerging country and the developed countries or the global equity markets is rather low (sometimes negative), such risk premium should be low. In fact, if the country offers significant future growth prospects (as in Cyprus due to its gas), the risk premium may actually be negative due to the growth option and positive skewness of returns. That is in line with recent market evidence on growth stocks. In sum, in countries with significant growth prospects, the variable rate on the GDP-bonds might even be lower than the fixed rate on an equivalent normal loan. There is also a concern about delays or possible manipulation of reported GDP growth which may cause uncertainty in the interest payments. The involvement of Eurostat (for eurozone members) would ensure reliability of statistics to alleviate these concerns. A variant that does not suffer from this problem is commodity-linked bonds, such as a bond linked to natural gas prices that might be quite suitable for the case of Cyprus. Many emerging countries that have natural resources can benefit from such instruments. Commodity prices are reported with no delays and have an established market record, in spot, futures and other derivative transactions. Cyprus has significant growth potential due to its gas reserves which could provide additional insurance through an extra option: a GDP linked-bond convertible into gas. Part B An alternative to current (failed) Eurozone bailout policies is to consider GDP-linked bonds, which in the case of Cyprus might also be convertible into natural gas. This might work as follows. International investors would be invited to buy these convertible bonds at various denominations, say from 25 M, 100 M, 500 M, up to one billion Euro, corresponding to specific quantities of future natural gas delivery (potentially in Cyprus’s economic zone), to raise a total of 17 billion Euro (the estimate for bailing out Cyprus). Each bond would have a maturity of, say, 15 or 20 years. In the first 10 years the bond simply pays a variable-coupon interest linked to Cyprus’s GDP growth +/- spread. The spread can be set by standard financial practices, taking account of the growth options given to investors. After 10 years (a conversion-protection period), the bond can be converted into specific amounts of natural gas (depending on the denomination chosen) to be purchased, for example at a 10% discount to the current price. Conversion times after year 10 could be graduated or alternative bond denominations may allow conversion in different subperiods to preclude all investors exercising at the same time and producing a (predictable) future shock in the spot market for Cypriot gas. The above conversion option has a market price determinable today that can offset part of the loan repayment or can be converted into an equivalent reduction in the spread and interest payments on the loan. In the early years when Cyprus’ GDP growth is low and the economy struggling, the country will benefit from the subsidized lower interest payments to be able to recover. Within a decade, as gas growth prospects materialize and GDP growth rises, investors can choose to keep it as a bond receiving higher GDP-linked payments or convert it into specified amounts of natural gas at the set discount price. The latter option will provide investors more assurance about the hybrid loan’s upside potential. Gas prices are less subject to potential manipulation or mismanagement by the government than GDP growth statistics, gas revenues, government budgets or the future state of the domestic economy. In effect, the gas linked option collaterizes the loan with gas, reducing its riskiness thereby lowering the interest rate. In case future economic growth slackens instead of picking up investors will convert to gas. The above may also have implications for the cost of funding of the gas venture itself. Neither the GDP-linked bond nor a bond convertible into a commodity (such as gas or cotton) are really new ideas (though their suggested combination here might be). Exactly 150 years ago (on March 19, 1863), in the midst of a losing Civil War, The Confederate States of America (the eleven Southern states that seceded from the Union to preserve slavery and their cotton plantations), issued a 7% Coupon bond, convertible into cotton (the “Cotton” Loan). At the time, cotton was the analogue of what oil and gas is today for the global economy (the textile-driven industrial economies of England and France were heavily dependent on cotton). The bond was issued in five European cities and raised $8.5 Million at the time. It offered a clause permitting conversion into cotton (deliverable in Southern Confederate ports) at a specified price per pound. They were offered in 4 denominations (e.g., 1,000 £ or 25,000 Fr for 40,000 lbs of cotton). Whereas the price of a Southern straight-bond issued in Amsterdam at the same time plummeted each time the South lost a battle and the probability of default rose, the price of cotton rose and the convertible bond gained value in the midst of an ugly civil war. The cotton convertible bonds effectively provided a hedge against the risk of war and was a common sense solution to Southern funding. The cotton convertible bond was a huge success. Ships were rented from Europe to take delivery in Southern ports, bypassing the Union’s blockade. It was a win-win business deal for the European lenders and the issuing government alike that took center stage and marginalized politics. Although the economic and military prospects for the South were deteriorating daily, and the probability of default rising, Europeans focused primarily on the prospects in the price of cotton in valuing the cotton-linked loans and funded the South generously. Shouldn’t we all (the EU Commission, the Troika, the Cyprus government) take lessons from (financial) history? After repeated failed attempts of half-baked policies that have curtailed growth prospects, shouldn’t we take another look at other common sense win-win alternatives? 150 years ago the Southerners and Europeans relied on common business sense. Why can’t we do the same today? The case of Cyprus currently confronting the Eurozone provides a unique opportunity, due to gas growth prospects, for the EU and global financial institutions to try out a novel common-sense approach. European policy makers should stay clear of suggestions for “haircuts” in uninsured bank deposits. No self-respecting economist or lender would countenance proposals that would kill the chance of recovery and damage financial credibility. A loss of confidence in the safety of Eurozone bank deposits tested in Cyprus will not only destroy the banking system and professional services’ sector of the island nation, but will produce contagion effects that will reverberate through the European and global financial systems. Lenos Trigeorgis holds a PhD (DBA) from Harvard University and is the Bank of Cyprus Chair Professor of Finance at the University of Cyprus and President of the Real Options Group. He has been a Visiting Professor of Finance at the London Business School. He is the author of Real Options (MIT Press, 1996), Strategic Investment (Princeton University Press, 2004) and Competitive Strategy (MIT Press, 2011).
1.The position that we are all together in this crisis is one put forward by politicians .Is this the case?Banks need billions,somebody has to pay.In any other case it is obvious who pays the cost.A supermarket goes bankrupt,suppliers and other creditors take the hit as employees of the supermarket and its suppliers join the unemployment lines.The same for all private companies.Why should this be different?Banks owe billions to depositors,they have lost all their capital and part of the depositors money.Instead of doing the obvious ,restructuring the Bank debts all the people are expected to foot the bill.
2.The gas belongs to all the people of Cyprus.Assuming the proposal of the Professor is feasible what happens is that the lenders(investors)will get the gas to pay the debt of the banks.Have the people of Cyprus been asked and voted they want to give the wealth of future generations to save the banks?
3.One bank has already been nationalised at the time the current Minister of Finance was its Chairman.Its employees have suffered salary cuts ,a big loss in deposits and now read in the papers that their bank is up for sale,that is it might not be bailed out.At the same time,the other Bank did not advise that it also needed capital .Its employees did not suffer any salary cuts ,some left with golden parachutes.Now we read in the press that PIMCO reports both banks need the same amount of capital.Why should there be this discrimination and is it fair to punish the one who revealed its true position?
4.Against all these arguments comes the last paragraph of the article of Professor Trigiorgis that if a deposit tax is imposed in Cyprus there will be losses to the service industry and a bank run in the Eurozone.Of course the service industry will be affected but is this is not fair?The alternative is to take over the pension funds,sell government property and load the people with a huge loan they will have to make sacrifices for ages.Somebody has to pay,our disagreement is who.Regarding the contagion to other countries I do not share the view,nobody will take notice except other bankrupt banks .Unless this happens we will not know the side effects.The same argument was made with the Greek bonds and yet a haircut was imposed.
I agree with the Professor that Cyprus and Europe should investigate the possibility of issuing gas backed bonds but independent of any decisions.The European leaders being far from the Cypriot establishment should act in the interest of all Cypriots and Europeans and force losses with fairness on everybody.Those who benefit from the current financial model should pay if they want it to remain unchanged.If they are not willing to pay the bill I can only hope our European allies will take the right decisions ,refocus and restart the economy.
Το ερώτημα που τίθεται ενώπιο μας είναι κατά πόσον ‘‘οιοσδήποτε δικαιολογείται να ενεργεί βεβιασμένα όταν οι συνθήκες είναι εμφανώς δυσμενείς και ο ίδιος ευρίσκεται σε κατάσταση πανικού’’; Παραδείγματος χάριν, όταν συμβεί ένα οδικό ατύχημα ή άλλη ανωμαλία στον αυτοκινητόδρομο, ένας οδηγός θεωρείται νουνεχής αν συνεχίσει την πορεία του μέσα από τα ακάμωτα χωράφια ή αν περιμένει ως ότου επιστρέψει η ομαλότητα;
Αυτή τη στιγμή η Κυπριακή Δημοκρατία ταλανίζεται από τη διεθνή οικονομική κρίση και τις απερίσκεπτες πολιτικές του παρελθόντος. Υπάρχουν τόσα πολλά ανοιχτά θέματα και αναπάντητα ερωτήματα που ουδείς σοβαρός χρηματοδότης θα επιθυμούσε να μας δανείσει μόνο στη βάση των μελλοντικών εξαγωγών υδρογονανθράκων.
Όμως, χάρη στη συμμετοχή μας στην Ευρωπαϊκή Ένωση και στις μεταρρυθμίσεις που έχουμε αποδεχθεί, ολοκληρώνονται οι διαδικασίες δανειοδότησής μας με όρους πολύ πιο συμφέροντες από ότι θα πληρώναμε αν εκδίδαμε χρεόγραφα (i) συνδεδεμένα με τον ρυθμό οικονομικής ανάπτυξης και (ii) μετατρέψιμα σε ποσότητες φυσικού αερίου.
Συναφώς, τονίζεται ότι όλα τα χρεόγραφα των οποίων οι αποδόσεις εξαρτώνται από απρόβλεπτα γεγονότα συνοδεύονται από ετήσια δαπάνη πολύ μεγάλων ασφαλίστρων (premiums) που απαιτούν οι χρηματοδότες ώστε να καλύψουν τυχόν διαφορές ανάμεσα:
• στα μεταβλητά επιτόκια που απορρέουν από π.χ. αμφίβολους ρυθμούς ανάπτυξης και ασταθείς αξίες προϊόντων και
• τα σταθερά επιτόκια με τα οποία μπορούν να δανείσουν αξιόχρεα κράτη για παρόμοιες χρονικές περιόδους.
Ευτυχώς, στο άρθρο του ο καθηγητής Τριγιώργης αφήνει να φανεί ότι χρεόγραφα που είναι συνδεδεμένα με ρυθμούς ανάπτυξης και προπωλήσεις αγαθών, κλπ, είναι χρηματοοικονομικά προϊόντα υψηλού κινδύνου τόσο για εκείνους που τα εκδίδουν όσο για εκείνους που τα αποδέχονται. Ως τέτοια, δεν προσφέρονται προς χρήση από σοβαρά κράτη τα οποία δεν κερδοσκοπούν σε βάρος των πολιτών τους, όσο πλούσιοι και αν είναι ή θα γίνουν οι τελευταίοι.
Derivatives is one of the main causes that got the World into this mess in the first place. Just as it is illegal to gain from another's demise in insurance so it should be in the financial markets. The promise of financial derivatives and options in the real world has sadly not materialised and the practice of such complex instuments by banks and financial intermediaries have slowed down the world economy, causing economic distortions and misallocation of capital. It surely is not the business of banks for example to gamble away, often betting against the interests of their clients. Nor is it the business of Govts to take such risks on. The world has lost touch with what is going on in the real economy and everyone is more concerned on how to grab more from the ever decreasing world economic pie. I think it is high time to go back to basics. Banks should be just banks (not be involved in equity or insurance) - bring back the Glass Steagull Act. Govts. should be confined to taxing their people if they want to spend more, rather than imposing upon them indirect taxation through ever increasing and more sophisticated ways of getting deeper and deeper into debt. I think we should be talking about the basics regarding risk and return and economic development in a real economy rather than putting our brain power in endless mathematical and financial exercises.
I think that if the Eurozone leaders understood the problem to be one of default instead of liquidity they had only to look at how the USA delat with Latin America with Brady bonds which were secured, for their principle, on USA Treasury bonds and brought down the cost of borrowing for the Latin Amercian countries which issued them. These were issued under various terms (fixed or floating) in view of investor demand for such bonds. The bonds were liquid and tradebale because investors were able to price such bonds. The countries which recovered were able to buy back the bonds outstanding and issue their own issues subesequently. Hence, if the eurozone had apprecaited the benefit of Brady bonds they could have used German government bonds (zero coupons incorporated to provide the redemption proceeds) to guarantee the principle and for the coupon to reflect the cost for the issuer. A structured bond which would have allowed Greece, and Cyprus for that matter, to be able to go to the interantional markets much earlier than at present.
The Professor is right in suggesting that Cyprus could issue bonds with warrants or convertible to some amount of gas at a price set today but the real issue is whether there is certainty about the availability of gas and how does one price and trade such bonds. At some future date this will be open to Cyprus but not at present and it is very constructtive to consider what options will be available to the Debt management authority in Cyprus. Funding of this nature is called reserve based funding and in the USA this is quite acceptable for shale gas which is less risky and more predictable. In a year or two we could be revisiting the ideas of the professor.
I believe that almost all economists, politicians and the general public are in total ignorance about what is the true underlying reason for the current world economic, banking, sovereign-debt crises etc.
I find it ASTONISHING that most bankers, economists, politicians, lawyers and in general almost everyone cannot anwser a couple of very basic questions which are the following:
WHAT IS MONEY? or HOW IS MONEY CREATED?
Try to answer this question – i bet most of you will get it wrong.
Once you realise that the answer to the question is that in today’s monetary and economic system Money = Debt and Money is created by banks through the fractional reserve banking system and then you start to explore this topic in more depth, then you will finally start to see the light.
In my humble opinion what is failing today (this has actually been failing since inception – although now its consequences are starting to become obvious) is the world’s MONETARY SYSTEM.
What needs to take place and what economists should be really talking about is MONETARY REFORM. This eventually WILL take place but unfortunately too late and only when the world economy is on the brink of total destuction (i suspect in the next 10-20 years).
The current monetary setup and economic system which includes (among other) the following main notions or participants:
1)Central Banks
2) Fractional Reserve Banking system
3)The fact that historically bank deposits worldwide are secured (in the sense that historically depositors have always been bailed out)
4)Financial Derivatives! (this is not part of the monetary structure but something that was probably created because of it and that has only accelerated the downfall of the system (and probably disguised the real reasons).
5) Last but not least HUMAN NATURE (greediness, corruption etc)
is FLAWED. It’s simply not functional and in the long run creates the SYMPTOMS that are observed today (Asset, stock and other bubbles, Non performing loans and thus failing banks, Bankrupt nations with unsustainable debts, Bailouts, Devaluation of currencies, Destruction of wealth etc etc etc).
A good doctor is the one that when presented with many symptoms determines the real ROOT of the problem and then consequently treats it. In the context of the current world economic situation which presents many (many, many…) symptoms most economists (“doctors”) misdiagnose the problem completely.
Arthur Schopenhauer (german philosopher) famously quoted (on the way ideas progress through a culture):
“All truth passes through three stages:
First it is ridiculed;
Second it is violently opposed;
Third, it is accepted as self evident.”
I suspect this is the most likely path that will be followed until most people finally realise that the real root cause of the world’s economic turmoil is the monetary system.
PS. http://www.positivemoney.org - this is an excellent website for further reading and possible solution to problem.
Η απόφαση για κούρεμα των καταθέσεων είναι μια Ιατρική θεραπεία του 15 αιώνα. Αυτό θα το εξηγήσω μετά απο 7-8 μέρες . Στο Ιδιο άρθρο θα αναφέρω και τι έπρεπε να γίνει ΠΡΙΝ απο μια τέτοια απόφαση.
Δέν θα γράψω οτιδήποτε άλλο τώρα , επιδή το κλίμα θα είναι πολύ τεταμένο στις επόμενες μέρες και δέν θέλω να το κάνω χειρότερο.
Αυτά που θα ακολουθήσουν στις επόμενες μέρες θα είναι πρωτόγνωρα για το ευρωπιακά δεδομένα και για την Κύπρο , Κάναμε τεραστια λάθη και συνεχίζουμε να κάνουμε ....
Καλό κουράγιο σε όλους, έρχονται πολύ δύσκολες μέρες για όλους μας....